The history of money concerns
the development of means of carrying out transactions involving a physical
medium of exchange. Money is any clearly identifiable object of value that is
generally accepted as payment for goods and services and repayment of debts
within a market or which is legal tender within a country.
Many things have been used as
medium of exchange in markets including, for example, livestock and sacks of
cereal grain (from which the Shekel is derived) – things directly useful in
themselves, but also sometimes merely attractive items such as cowry shells or
beads were exchanged for more useful commodities. Precious metals from which
early coins were made fall into this second category.
Numismatics is the scientific
study of money and its history in all its varied forms.
Non-monetary exchange
In Politics Book 1:9[1] (c.350
B.C.) the Greek philosopher Aristotle contemplated on the nature of money. He
considered that every object has two uses, the first being the original purpose
for which the object was designed, and the second possibility is to conceive of
the object as an item to sell or barter. The assignment of monetary value to an
otherwise insignificant object such as a coin or promissory note arises as
people and their trading associate evolve a psychological capacity to place
trust in each other and in external authority within barter exchange.
With barter, an individual
possessing any surplus of value, such as a measure of grain or a quantity of
livestock could directly exchange that for something perceived to have similar
or greater value or utility, such as a clay pot or a tool. The capacity to
carry out barter transactions is limited in that it depends on a coincidence of
wants. The seller of food grain has to find the buyer who wants to buy grain
and who also could offer in return something the seller wants to buy. There is
no agreed standard measure into which both seller and buyer could exchange
commodities according to their relative value of all the various goods and
services offered by other potential barter partners.
Gift economy
In a gift economy, valuable
goods and services are regularly given without any explicit agreement for
immediate or future rewards (i.e. there is no formal quid pro quo). Ideally, simultaneous
or recurring giving serves to circulate and redistribute valuables within the
community.
There are various social
theories concerning gift economies. Some consider the gifts to be a form of
reciprocal altruism. Another interpretation is that implicit "I owe
you" debt[8] and social status are awarded in return for the
"gifts". Consider for example, the sharing of food in some
hunter-gatherer societies, where food-sharing is a safeguard against the
failure of any individual's daily foraging. This custom may reflect altruism,
it may be a form of informal insurance, or may bring with it social status or
other benefits.
The emergence of money
Anatolian obsidian as a raw
material for stone-age tools was distributed as early as 12,000 B.C., with
organized trade occurring in the 9th millennium.(Cauvin;Chataigner 1998) In
Sardinia, one of the four main sites for sourcing the material deposits of
obsidian within the Mediterranean, trade in this was replaced in the 3rd
millennium by trade in copper and silver.
As early as 9000 BC both grain
and cattle were used as money or as barter (Davies) (the first grain remains
found, considered to be evidence of pre-agricultural practice date to 17,000
BC).The importance of grain with respect to the value of money is inherent in
language where the term for a small quantity of gold was "grain of
gold".
In the earliest instances of
trade with money, the things with the greatest utility and reliability in terms
of re-use and re-trading of these things (their marketability), determined the
nature of the object or thing chosen to exchange. So as in agricultural
societies, things needed for efficient and comfortable employment of energies
for the production of cereals and the like were the most easy to transfer to
monetary significance for direct exchange. As more of the basic conditions of
the human existence were met to the satisfaction of human needs,so the division
of labour increased to create new activities for the use of time to solve more
advanced concerns. As people's needs became more refined, so indirect exchange
became more likely as the physical separation of skilled labourers (suppliers)
from their prospective clients (demand) required the use of a medium common to
all communities, to facilitate a wider market.
Early administration
The Code of Hammurabi, the best
preserved ancient law code, was created ca. 1760 BC (middle chronology) in
ancient Babylon. It was enacted by the sixth Babylonian king, Hammurabi.
Earlier collections of laws include the code of Ur-Nammu, king of Ur (ca. 2050
BC), the Code of Eshnunna (ca. 1930 BC) and the code of Lipit-Ishtar of Isin
(ca. 1870 BC).[29] These law codes formalized the role of money in civil
society. They set amounts of interest on debt... fines for 'wrongdoing'... and
compensation in money for various infractions of formalized law.
The Mesopotamian civilization
developed a large scale economy based on commodity money. The Babylonians and
their neighboring city states later developed the earliest system of economics
as we think of it today, in terms of rules on debt, legal contracts and law
codes relating to business practices and private property. Money was not only
an emergence, it was a necessity.
Early usage
The earliest places of storage
were thought to be money-boxes containments (θΗΕΑΤΡΟΕ) made similar to the construction
of a bee-hive, as of the Mycenae tombs of 1550–1500 BC.
An early type of money were
cattle, which were used as such from between 9000 to 6000 BCE onwards (Davies
1996 & 1999) Both the animal and the manure produced were valuable; animals
are recorded as being used as payment as in Roman law where fines were paid in
oxen and sheep (Rollin 1836) and within the Iliad and Odyssey, attesting to a
value c.850–800 BCE (Evans & Schmalensee 2005).
It has long been assumed that
metals, where available, were favored for use as proto-money over such
commodities as cattle, cowry shells, or salt, because metals are at once
durable, portable, and easily divisible. The use of gold as proto-money has
been traced back to the fourth millennium BC when the Egyptians used gold bars
of a set weight as a medium of exchange, as had been done earlier in
Mesopotamia with silver bars.
The first mention of the use of
money within the Bible is within the book "Genesis"in reference to
criteria of the circumcision of a bought slave. Later, the Cave of Machpelah is
purchased (with argentum by Abraham, during a period dated as being the
beginning of the twentieth century B.C.E., some-time recent to 1900 B.C.E.
(after 1985). The currency was also in use amongst the Philistine people of the
same time-period.
The shekel was an ancient unit used
in Mesopotamia around 3000 BC to define both a specific weight of barley and
equivalent amounts of materials such as silver, bronze and copper. The use of a
single unit to define both mass and currency was a similar concept to the
British pound, which was originally defined as a one pound mass of silver.
A description of how trade
proceeded includes for sales the dividing (clipping) of an amount from a weight
of something corresponding to the perceived value of the purchase. Of this the
ancient Greek term was Κέρờς. From this one might understand the development of
how coinage was imagined from the small metallic clippings (of silver) resulting
from trade exchanges. The word used in Thucydides writings History for money is
chremata, translated in some contexts as "goods" or
"property", although with a wider ranging possible applicable usage,
having a definite meaning "valuable things".
The first gold coins of the
Grecian age were struck in Lydia at a time approximated to the year 700 B.C.E.
The talent in use during the periods of Grecian history both before and during
the time of the life of Homer, weighed between 8.42 and 8.75 grammes. (p. 3 –
Seltman)
Commodity money
Bartering has several problems,
most notably that it requires a "coincidence of wants". For example,
if a wheat farmer needs what a fruit farmer produces, a direct swap is
impossible as seasonal fruit would spoil before the grain harvest. A solution
is to trade fruit for wheat indirectly through a third,
"intermediate", commodity: the fruit is exchanged for the
intermediate commodity when the fruit ripens. If this intermediate commodity
doesn't perish and is reliably in demand throughout the year (e.g. copper,
gold, or wine) then it can be exchanged for wheat after the harvest. The
function of the intermediate commodity as a store-of-value can be standardized
into a widespread commodity money, reducing the coincidence of wants problem.
By overcoming the limitations of simple barter, a commodity money makes the
market in all other commodities more liquid.
Many cultures around the world
eventually developed the use of commodity money. Ancient China, Africa, and
India used cowry shells. Trade in Japan's feudal system was based on the koku –
a unit of rice. The shekel was an ancient unit of weight and currency. The
first usage of the term came from Mesopotamia circa 3000 BC and referred to a
specific weight of barley, which related other values in a metric such as
silver, bronze, copper etc. A barley/shekel was originally both a unit of currency
and a unit of weight.
Wherever trade is common,
barter systems usually lead quite rapidly to several key goods being imbued
with monetary properties. In the early British colony of New South Wales, rum
emerged quite soon after settlement as the most monetary of goods. When a
nation is without a currency it commonly adopts a foreign currency. In prisons
where conventional money is prohibited, it is quite common for cigarettes to
take on a monetary quality. Contrary to popular belief, precious metals have
rarely been used outside of large societies. Gold, in particular, is
sufficiently scarce that it has only been used as a currency for a few relatively
brief periods in history.
Standardized coinage
From approximately 1000 BC
money in the shape of small knives and spades made of bronze were in use in the
society of China, with cast bronze replicas of cowrie shells in use before
this. The first manufactured coins seems to have taken place separately in India,
China, and in cities around the Aegean sea between 700 and 500 BC.[67] While
these Aegean coins were stamped (heated and hammered with insignia), the Indian
coins (from the Ganges river valley) were punched metal disks, and Chinese
coins (first developed in the Great Plain) were cast bronze with holes in the
center to be strung together. The different forms and metallurgical process
implies a separate development.
The first ruler in the
Mediterranean known to have officially set standards of weight and money was
Pheidon. Minting occurred in the latter parts of the 7th century amongst the
cities of Grecian Asia Minor, spreading to Aegean parts of the Greek islands
and the south of Italy by 500 BC. The first stamped money (having the mark of
some authority in the form of a picture or words) can be seen in the
Bibliothèque Nationale of Paris. It is an electrum stater of a turtle coin,
coined at Aegina island. This coin dates about 700 BC.
Other coins made of Electrum (a
naturally occurring alloy of silver and gold) were manufactured on a larger
scale about 650 BC in Lydia (on the coast of what is now Turkey. Similar
coinage was adopted and manufactured to their own standards in nearby cities of
Ionia, including Mytilene and Phokaia (using coins of Electrum) and Aegina
(using silver) during the 6th century BC. and soon became adopted in mainland
Greece itself, and the Persian Empire (after it incorporated Lydia in 547 BC).
The use and export of silver
coinage, along with soldiers paid in coins, contributed to the Athenian
Empire's 5th century BC, dominance of the region. The silver used was mined in
southern Attica at Laurium and Thorikos by a huge workforce of slave labour. A
major silver vein discovery at Laurium in 483 BC led to the huge expansion of
the Athenian military fleet.
It was the discovery of the
touchstone which led the way for metal-based commodity money and coinage. Any
soft metal can be tested for purity on a touchstone, allowing one to quickly
calculate the total content of a particular metal in a lump. Gold is a soft
metal, which is also hard to come by, dense, and storable. As a result,
monetary gold spread very quickly from Asia Minor, where it first gained wide
usage, to the entire world.
Using such a system still
required several steps and mathematical calculation. The touchstone allows one
to estimate the amount of gold in an alloy, which is then multiplied by the
weight to find the amount of gold alone in a lump. To make this process easier,
the concept of standard coinage was introduced. Coins were pre-weighed and
pre-alloyed, so as long as the manufacturer was aware of the origin of the
coin, no use of the touchstone was required. Coins were typically minted by
governments in a carefully protected process, and then stamped with an emblem
that guaranteed the weight and value of the metal. It was, however, extremely
common for governments to assert that the value of such money lay in its emblem
and thus to subsequently reduce the value of the currency by lowering the
content of valuable metal.
Gold and silver were used as
the most common form of money throughout history. In many languages, such as
Spanish, French, and Italian, the word for silver is still directly related to
the word for money. Although gold and silver were commonly used to mint coins,
other metals were used. For instance, Ancient Sparta minted coins from iron to
discourage its citizens from engaging in foreign trade. In the early
seventeenth century Sweden lacked more precious metal and so produced
"plate money", which were large slabs of copper approximately 50 cm
or more in length and width, appropriately stamped with indications of their
value.
Gold coinage began to be minted
again in Europe in the thirteenth century. Frederick the II is credited with
having re-introduced the metal to currency during the time of the Crusades.
During the fourteenth century Europe had en masse converted from use of silver
in currency to minting of gold. Vienna transferred from minting silver to
instead gold during 1328.
Metal based coins had the
advantage of carrying their value within the coins themselves – on the other
hand, they induced manipulations: the clipping of coins in the attempt to get
and recycle the precious metal. A greater problem was the simultaneous
co-existence of gold, silver and copper coins in Europe. English and Spanish
traders valued gold coins more than silver coins, as many of their neighbors did,
with the effect that the English gold-based guinea coin began to rise against
the English silver based crown in the 1670s and 1680s. Consequently, silver was
ultimately pulled out of England for dubious amounts of gold coming into the
country at a rate no other European nation would share. The effect was worsened
with Asian traders not sharing the European appreciation of gold altogether —
gold left Asia and silver left Europe in quantities European observers like
Isaac Newton, Master of the Royal Mint observed with unease.
Stability came into the system
with national Banks guaranteeing to change money into gold at a promised rate;
it did, however, not come easily. The Bank of England risked a national
financial catastrophe in the 1730s when customers demanded their money be
changed into gold in a moment of crisis. Eventually London's merchants saved
the bank and the nation with financial guarantees.
Another step in the evolution
of money was the change from a coin being a unit of weight to being a unit of
value. A distinction could be made between its commodity value and its specie
value. The difference is these values is seigniorage.
Trade bills of exchange
Bills of exchange became
prevalent with the expansion of European trade toward the end of the Middle
Ages. A flourishing Italian wholesale trade in cloth, woolen clothing, wine,
tin and other commodities was heavily dependent on credit for its rapid
expansion. Goods were supplied to a buyer against a bill of exchange, which
constituted the buyer's promise to make payment at some specified future date.
Provided that the buyer was reputable or the bill was endorsed by a credible
guarantor, the seller could then present the bill to a merchant banker and
redeem it in money at a discounted value before it actually became due. The
main purpose of these bills nevertheless was, that traveling with cash was
particularly dangerous at the time. A deposit could be made with a banker in
one town, in turn a bill of exchange was handed out, that could be redeemed in
another town.
These bills could also be used
as a form of payment by the seller to make additional purchases from his own
suppliers. Thus, the bills – an early form of credit – became both a medium of
exchange and a medium for storage of value. Like the loans made by the Egyptian
grain banks, this trade credit became a significant source for the creation of
new money. In England, bills of exchange became an important form of credit and
money during last quarter of the 18th century and the first quarter of the 19th
century before banknotes, checks and cash credit lines were widely available.
Tallies
The acceptance of symbolic
forms of money opened up vast new realms for human creativity. A symbol could
be used to represent something of value that was available in physical storage
somewhere else in space, such as grain in the warehouse. It could also be used
to represent something of value that would be available later in time, such as
a promissory note or bill of exchange, a document ordering someone to pay a
certain sum of money to another on a specific date or when certain conditions
have been fulfilled.
In the 12th century, the
English monarchy introduced an early version of the bill of exchange in the
form of a notched piece of wood known as a tally stick. Tallies originally came
into use at a time when paper was rare and costly, but their use persisted
until the early 19th Century, even after paper forms of money had become
prevalent. The notches were used to denote various amounts of taxes payable to
the crown. Initially tallies were simply used as a form of receipt to the tax
payer at the time of rendering his dues. As the revenue department became more
efficient, they began issuing tallies to denote a promise of the tax assessee
to make future tax payments at specified times during the year. Each tally
consisted of a matching pair – one stick was given to the assessee at the time
of assessment representing the amount of taxes to be paid later and the other
held by the Treasury representing the amount of taxes be collected at a future
date.
The Treasury discovered that
these tallies could also be used to create money. When the crown had exhausted
its current resources, it could use the tally receipts representing future tax
payments due to the crown as a form of payment to its own creditors, who in
turn could either collect the tax revenue directly from those assessed or use
the same tally to pay their own taxes to the government. The tallies could also
be sold to other parties in exchange for gold or silver coin at a discount
reflecting the length of time remaining until the taxes was due for payment.
Thus, the tallies became an accepted medium of exchange for some types of
transactions and an accepted medium for store of value. Like the girobanks
before it, the Treasury soon realized that it could also issue tallies that
were not backed by any specific assessment of taxes. By doing so, the Treasury
created new money that was backed by public trust and confidence in the
monarchy rather than by specific revenue receipts.
Goldsmith bankers
Goldsmiths in England had been
craftsmen, bullion merchants, money changers and money lenders since the 16th
century. But they were not the first to act as financial intermediates; in the
early 17th century, the scriveners were the first to keep deposits for the
express purpose of relending them. Merchants and traders had amassed huge
hoards of gold and entrusted their wealth to the Royal Mint for storage. In
1640 King Charles I seized the private gold stored in the mint as a forced loan
(which was to be paid back over time). Thereafter merchants preferred to store
their gold with the goldsmiths of London, who possessed private vaults, and
charged a fee for that service. In exchange for each deposit of precious metal,
the goldsmiths issued receipts certifying the quantity and purity of the metal
they held as a bailee (i.e. in trust). These receipts could not be assigned
(only the original depositor could collect the stored goods). Gradually the
goldsmiths took over the function of the scriveners of relending on behalf of a
depositor and also developed modern banking practices; promissory notes were
issued for money deposited which by custom and/or law was a loan to the goldsmith,
i.e. the depositor expressly allowed the goldsmith to use the money for any
purpose including advances to his customers. The goldsmith charged no fee, or
even paid interest on these deposits. Since the promissory notes were payable
on demand, and the advances (loans) to the goldsmith's customers were repayable
over a longer time period, this was an early form of fractional reserve
banking. The promissory notes developed into an assignable instrument, which
could circulate as a safe and convenient form of money backed by the
goldsmith's promise to pay. Hence goldsmiths could advance loans in the form of
gold money, or in the form of promissory notes, or in the form of checking
accounts. Gold deposits were relatively stable, often remaining with the
goldsmith for years on end, so there was little risk of default so long as public
trust in the goldsmith's integrity and financial soundness was maintained.
Thus, the goldsmiths of London became the forerunners of British banking and
prominent creators of new money based on credit.
Demand deposits
The primary business of the
early merchant banks was promotion of trade. The new class of commercial banks
made accepting deposits and issuing loans their principal activity. They lend
the money they received on deposit. They created additional money in the form
of new bank notes. The money they created was partially backed by gold, silver
or other assets and partially backed only by public trust in the institutions
that created it.
Demand deposits are funds that
are deposited in bank accounts and are available for withdrawal at the
discretion of the depositor. The withdrawal of funds from the account does not
require contacting or making any type of prior arrangements with the bank or
credit union. As long as the account balance is sufficient to cover the amount
of the withdrawal, and the withdrawal takes place in accordance with procedures
set in place by the financial institution, the funds may be withdrawn on demand
Banknotes
Paper money was introduced in
Song Dynasty China during the 11th century. The development of the banknote
began in the seventh century, with local issues of paper currency. Its roots
were in merchant receipts of deposit during the Tang Dynasty (618–907), as
merchants and wholesalers desired to avoid the heavy bulk of copper coinage in
large commercial transactions. The issue of credit notes is often for a limited
duration, and at some discount to the promised amount later. The jiaozi
nevertheless did not replace coins during the Song Dynasty; paper money was
used alongside the coins. The central government soon observed the economic
advantages of printing paper money, issuing a monopoly right of several of the
deposit shops to the issuance of these certificates of deposit. By the early
12th century, the amount of banknotes issued in a single year amounted to an
annual rate of 26 million strings of cash coins.
In the 13th century, paper
money became known in Europe through the accounts of travelers, such as Marco Polo
and William of Rubruck. Marco Polo's account of paper money during the Yuan Dynasty
is the subject of a chapter of his book, The Travels of Marco Polo, titled
"How the Great Kaan Causeth the Bark of Trees, Made into Something Like
Paper, to Pass for Money All Over his Country." In medieval Italy and
Flanders, because of the insecurity and impracticality of transporting large
sums of money over long distances, money traders started using promissory
notes. In the beginning these were personally registered, but they soon became
a written order to pay the amount to whoever had it in their possession. These
notes can be seen as a predecessor to regular banknotes. The first European
banknotes were issued by Stockholms Banco, a predecessor of the Bank of Sweden,
in 1661. These replaced the copper-plates being used instead as a means of
payment,[94] although in 1664 the bank ran out of coins to redeem notes and
ceased operating in the same year.
Inspired by the success of the
London goldsmiths, some of which became the forerunners of great English banks,
banks began issuing paper notes quite properly termed ‘banknotes’ which
circulated in the same way that government issued currency circulates today. In
England this practice continued up to 1694. Scottish banks continued issuing
notes until 1850. In USA, this practice continued through the 19th Century,
where at one time there were more than 5000 different types of bank notes
issued by various commercial banks in America. Only the notes issued by the
largest, most creditworthy banks were widely accepted. The script of smaller, lesser
known institutions circulated locally. Farther from home it was only accepted
at a discounted rate, if it was accepted at all. The proliferation of types of
money went hand in hand with a multiplication in the number of financial
institutions.
These banknotes were a form of
representative money which could be converted into gold or silver by
application at the bank. Since banks issued notes far in excess of the gold and
silver they kept on deposit, sudden loss of public confidence in a bank could
precipitate mass redemption of banknotes and result in bankruptcy.
The use of bank notes issued by
private commercial banks as legal tender has gradually been replaced by the
issuance of bank notes authorized and controlled by national governments. The
Bank of England was granted sole rights to issue banknotes in England after
1694. In the USA, the Federal Reserve Bank was granted similar rights after its
establishment in 1913. Until recently, these government-authorized currencies
were forms of representative money, since they were partially backed by gold or
silver and were theoretically convertible into gold or silver.
(Source: http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/History_of_money)
The Story of Philippine money by
Atty. Ignacio R. Bunye
From the beadlike form of
pre-colonial Philippine money, to the early coins and notes of the Spanish
period and the Philippine revolutionary government, the face of our country’s
currency has evolved significantly through the years.
According to a history of
Philippine money collated by the Bangko Sentral ng Pilipinas, the American
period paved the way for an important development in this monetary evolution.The Americans, according to the
BSP, instituted a new monetary system for the Philippines based on gold and
pegged the Philippine peso to the American dollar at the ratio of 2:1.
The US Congress, it can be
recalled, had approved the Coinage Act for the Philippines in 1903.
The coins minted under the new
system bore the designs of Filipino engraver and artist, Melecio Figueroa.
One-half centavo to one-peso denominations were issued by the American regime.
The BSP noted that the renaming
of El Banco Espanol Filipino to Bank of the Philippine Islands in 1912 resulted
in the use of English from Spanish in all notes and coins issued up to 1933.
Starting May 1918, treasury
certificates replaced the silver certificates series, and a one-peso note was
added.
During the Japanese Occupation,
two kinds of notes circulated in the country: the big-denomination war notes
issued by the Japanese and the guerrilla notes or resistance currencies issued
by provinces and municipalities.
Most of the resistance
currencies were sanctioned by the Philippine government in-exile and partially
redeemed after the war.
When the Philippines gained
independence after World War II, the Philippine Republic used old treasury
certificates overprinted with the word “Victory” as currency.
In 1949, the creation of the
Central Bank of the Philippines paved the way for the issuance of the first
currencies in the form of English series notes printed by the Thomas de la Rue
& Co., Ltd. in England and the coins minted at the United States Bureau of
Mint.
According to the BSP, the
Filipinization of the Philippine Republic’s coins and paper money began in the
late 1960s and continues to this day.
In the 1970s, the Marcos
government issued the Ang Bagong Lipunan (ABL) series notes, which were printed
at the BSP’s Security Printing Plant in Quezon City beginning 1978.
With the introduction of flora
and fauna coins in 1983, a new wave of change swept through the Philippine
coinage system. The series featured national heroes and species of flora and fauna.
Ten years after the new design
series of banknotes issued in 1985 replaced the ABL series, a new set of coins
and notes were again issued—this time carrying the BSP logo.
We now look forward to the
impending release of the New Generation Currency at the end of this year, with
its exciting new design and security features.
This new currency will again
bring to the Filipino consciousness the message repeatedly reflected in the
evolution of Philippine money under the Philippine Republic: that we are indeed
a nation in command of our destiny.
(Source: http://thepinoy.com/?p=5162)
(Source: http://thepinoy.com/?p=5162)
No comments:
Post a Comment