Depressions are generated by the same factors that cause a recession. You can look at depression as an extended recession on the graph of the business cycle wave. Unemployment rises, gross domestic product (GDP) drops off,stock prices fall and the stock market crashes.
In simple terms, depressions are really protracted versions of recessions. In February 2008, the unemployment rate in the U.S. was 4.8 percent [source: Bureau of Labor Statistics]. But it wasn't until March 2008 that economists began to seriously consider that the economy was entering a recession. By contrast, during the Great Depression unemployment grew from 3 percent before the stock market crash of 1929 to 25 percent in 1933 [source: Bernanke]. In that same period, the U. S. gross domestic product fell by nearly half, from $103.8 billion to $55.7 billion [source: National Parks Service].
While no one wants to see the country in a depression, not everyone views a recession as a bad thing. The National Bureau of Economic Research says that expansion -- the opposite of recession, represented by the upward movement of the market wave -- is the normal state of a market [source: NBER]. But some economists take more of a Zen approach, considering recession as neither bad nor good, but part of a natural market cycle. When the Federal Reserve Bank steps in to adjust interest rates, some say this actually tampers with the natural order of the economy. Even worse, some economists believe that changing interest rates to pump up a recessing market can make matters worse by extending the decline. However, few people seem to resist when the Fed adjusts markets during a recession. (Source: http://money.howstuffworks.com/recession-and-depression2.htm)
The Great Recession of 2008–09:
Year In Review 2009
When 2009 dawned, no one knew
whether the global financial crisis that had burst into full bloom the previous
autumn would develop into the second Great Depression. Twelve months later,
what many called the Great Recession showed signs of coming to an end, and the
worst appeared to have been averted. On the whole, private economists applauded
the U.S. government’s response to the crisis at hand, but some of the remedies
enacted there and in other countries seemed poised to haunt the world economy in
years to come.
Even if the financial crisis
did not send the world back to the 1930s, it turned economic growth into
contraction in many countries and slowed expansion practically everywhere else.
The ripple effects of the financial crisis ranged far beyond the financial.
Governments fell in Iceland and Latvia. The Chinese brushed aside pleas for
more accommodating human rights and currency valuation policies. European
political union was put under strain. Japan proposed only weak measures to
combat climate change.
Most of the major industrial
democracies adopted domestic government programs designed to awaken their
slumbering economies; the U.S. package, at $787 billion, was the biggest. The
world’s economic outlook brightened as the year proceeded, however, and most
countries began growing again in mid-2009 after recessions that were, for most,
the deepest since the Great Depression. In a rare exception, China escaped the
slump; if anything, the global recession burnished China’s apparent ambition to
challenge U.S. dominance in the global economy.
The U.S. Leads the Way
The U.S. housing market was the
domino that, when it fell, toppled many of the world’s major economies and led
the world into recession. For the first half of the decade, aggressive
investing by homebuyers, mortgage lenders, Wall Street investment houses, and
insurers had driven up the median price of a single-family home by almost 10% a
year, with housing in some parts of the country escalating even faster. When
home prices headed back down in 2007, large numbers of homeowners faced rising
adjustable-rate mortgage payments and/or could no longer borrow against a
rising home value to finance other expenses. By the middle of 2009, the median
home price had fallen close to its 2000 level. Those with heavy investments in
housing, including risky mortgage-backed securities, found them all but
worthless. The government stepped in with a massively expensive bailout program
in late 2008 and continuing into 2009.
The devastation to the U.S.
economy spread far beyond housing. The banking industry was especially hard
hit. (See Sidebar.) Altogether, 176 banks in the U.S. failed in 2009, many of
them small and local. Even financially secure banks, not trusting potential
borrowers to pay them back, stopped lending. Businesses—especially small and
new businesses—could not find the credit that they needed to pay creditors or
buy inventory or to pay their own workers, much less to hire new ones. Even
short-term interest rates close to zero did not fully thaw credit markets.
Businesses that relied on their customers’ ability to secure loans had a rough
time. Automakers General Motors (GM) and Chrysler, both of which reorganized
after brief trips through bankruptcy in 2009, qualified for bailout money. The
overall economic slowdown sent stock prices reeling, with the benchmark Dow
Jones Industrial Average (DJIA) sinking by about 54% in the 17 months from the
market high in October 2007 to the trough in March 2009.
As 2009 began, comparisons with
the Great Depression were as common as foreclosed houses in Nevada, but there
was one important difference: policy makers this time had the experience of the
Depression to guide them. They identified three policy areas where they vowed
not to make the same mistakes that seemed to have prolonged the Depression:
fiscal, monetary, and trade.
In the 1930s, national leaders
generally pledged allegiance to fiscal policies based on balanced budgets. With
tax revenue falling in tandem with economic growth, balancing budgets meant
cutting spending just when economies needed to stimulate business expansion and
job growth. This time around, however, political leaders poured money into such
projects as road construction and schools. Although some governments were more
aggressive than others, just about all countries joined the stimulus parade.
In 1929 the U.S. Federal
Reserve Board (Fed), seeking to restrain a speculative rise in stock prices,
instituted a monetary policy of tight money and high interest rates. The
economy predictably contracted, and the Depression officially began that
August. Nevertheless, the Fed further tightened its grip on the money supply in
1931, adding to the squeeze on the domestic economy. Through all of 2009,
however, the Fed held the Fed Funds rate (the interest rate that banks pay each
other for overnight loans) in a range of 0.0–0.25%. Most other central banks
also loosened monetary policy. The Fed and many of its foreign counterparts
also injected capital into banks and bought their shaky loans.
When economies go haywire,
there is a natural tendency to close ranks by tightening trade policy and
refraining from buying foreign goods. In 1930 the U.S. Congress enacted the
Smoot-Hawley import tariffs. Many U.S. trading partners followed suit. The
result was a decline in world trade volume estimated in late1932 at about 30%
and still growing, an outcome almost universally seen as having fueled the
Great Depression. This time there was no such rush to protect industry at home,
although worldwide trade actually dropped even more sharply in the current
financial crisis than during the beginning of the Depression. This was not the
result of new trade barriers; rather, the faltering global economy sapped
demand for goods and services, whether produced at home or abroad.
Enlightened decision making may
have blocked another Depression, but it could not prevent a great deal of
misery. The financial crisis struck individual countries with an impact that
depended heavily on two factors: whether local institutions had ties to the
U.S. financial sector and whether the local economy depended on export sales to
the West. Most of the developed countries had close financial and trade
relations with the U.S. Of the 33 countries that the International Monetary
Fund considered to have “advanced economies,” only Australia seemed likely to
avoid a period of contraction. The dynamic economies of Asia were well
positioned, and three large Asian countries—India, Indonesia, and China—escaped
relatively unscathed. At least in the short run, India benefited from having
isolated itself from the crosscurrents of the global economy. Japan’s economy,
the largest in the world after the U.S., was fused to the West’s, and Japan
marched alongside the West into recession. With a large economic stimulus
package in place, however, Japan pulled out of recession in the third quarter
of 2009. Fearful that strict limits on greenhouse gas emissions could cripple
the economic rebound, the Japanese government proposed weaker limits than those
under discussion in Europe and the U.S.
Europe, with its close
financial and trade ties to the U.S., stood in sharp contrast to Asia. Even
Norway, which had virtuously invested its North Sea oil revenue with
considerable prudence while the U.K. was spending its windfall on government
programs, could not escape recession. Norway slipped into a mild slump in late
2008 and emerged early in 2009. Most of the rest of Europe fared worse. Many
countries approved economic stimulus packages to extricate themselves from
recession, and many resumed economic growth, although the U.K., Spain, and
others remained in recession for the first nine months of 2009. In the fourth
quarter, the U.K. barely emerged from recession with growth of 0.1%. Reflecting
fears of future inflation, the stimulus programs in Europe were smaller than
those in the U.S. Perhaps more significant, the largesse stopped at national
borders. Germany, France, and other wealthy European Union countries defeated
Hungary’s request that the EU’s Western European members give $240 billion to
members in Eastern Europe to combat the slump.
Hardest hit were countries at
the four “corners” of Europe: Iceland, Latvia, Greece, and Spain. Iceland
became the first country to lose its government over the financial crisis.
Iceland’s three largest banks, privatized in the early 1990s, had grown fat on
securities trading, but they failed in 2008 when the financial crisis left them
unable to pay a mountain of foreign obligations. The conservative prime
minister resigned in January 2009 and was replaced by a leftist, Jóhanna
Sigurðardóttir, who promptly recapitalized the banks and started the process of
taking her fiercely reclusive country into the EU. International trade—or the
sudden lack of it—was Latvia’s undoing. Latvia had boasted Europe’s strongest
economic growth rate (10%) as recently as 2007. Then the tables turned, and the
Latvian economy shrank at double-digit rates in 2009—possibly the worst
performance in Europe, although its Baltic neighbours, Lithuania and Estonia,
were not far behind. In the Latvian capital of Riga, a street demonstration in
January to protest economic decline turned violent, and a month later the prime
minister resigned.
In Greece, where the budget
deficit reached nearly 13% of annual economic output (even greater than the 11%
in the U.S.), the three credit-rating services—Fitch, Moody’s, and Standard and
Poor’s—downgraded the country’s debt. At year’s end Greece had the lowest
credit rating of the 16 countries in the euro zone. That made it more expensive
for Greece to finance its debt, which at 130% of economic output was nearly the
highest in Europe. A default on its debt would be a giant headache not only for
Greece but also for the entire EU. Spain, whose budget deficit was rocketing
toward 11%, was on the same path as Greece, although less far along. Standard
and Poor’s also downgraded Spain, which started at a much higher level.
The fiscal problems that put
Greece and Spain on a slippery slope were common across Europe, especially
among economies that had grown the most (largely on borrowed money) during the
heady early years of the decade. Ireland, heretofore an EU success story, was a
typical case. The Irish government, determined not to let the budget deficit
reach 13%, proposed to raise taxes, cut benefits, and trim government workers’
pay. The U.S. Response
In the United States, the
government followed a two-pronged strategy to reverse the financial crisis:
bail out distressed financial institutions (lest they transmit their failure to
their creditors) and pump government money into the economy (to stimulate
business activity when private loans were scarce). What emerged from the
bailout was an extraordinary degree of government involvement in—and sometimes
even majority ownership of—the private sector. Altogether, the government by
late 2009 had provided an estimated $4 trillion to keep the financial sector
afloat. Many of the biggest bailout beneficiaries quickly paid the government
back, and the ultimate cost of the bailout to taxpayers was estimated at “only”
$1.2 trillion. Congress in February handed Pres. Barack Obama the first
legislative triumph of his month-old presidency when it enacted a $787 billion
fiscal stimulus bill that comprised $288 billion in tax cuts and $499 billion
in spending, most of it for public-works programs such as school construction
and highway repair. Although Republicans groused that checks for much of the
$499 billion would be issued too late to do any good, the nonpartisan
Congressional Budget Office said that thanks to the tax measures, about
three-quarters of the full $787 billion would be spent in 18 months. Obama
claimed that the bill would create or preserve 3.5 million jobs, a figure that
many of his opponents called far too optimistic.
Congress also played a role in
the bailout of failing financial institutions. At the end of 2008, Congress
enacted the Troubled Asset Relief Program (TARP) authorizing the Department of
the Treasury to invest up to $700 billion by buying unproductive real-estate
investments or even becoming part owners by purchasing financial company stock.
The Fed, using authority that it already had, played an even bigger role.
Printing more money when not enough was available, the central bank invested
heavily in foundering institutions and guaranteed the value of their shaky
assets. By the end of 2009, the government owned almost 80% of American
International Group (AIG), the country’s biggest insurer, at a cost of more
than $150 billion. It also owned 60% of GM and had a stake in some 700 banks.
It initially spent $111 billion to prop up Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac, the
companies sponsored by Congress to buy mortgages from their issuers. The
government promised to play no role in managing these companies and to sell its
ownership stakes as soon as practical. TARP provided the Treasury with only a
fraction of the funds used for the bailout, however. The Fed was responsible
for the lion’s share, and even the massive AIG rescue was engineered entirely
outside the legislated Treasury Department program.
Reflecting public views,
members of the government expressed outrage that some of the same executives
who helped precipitate the financial crisis should make millions of dollars a
year in salaries and bonuses. Treasury Secretary Timothy Geithner appointed a
“special master for executive compensation” to review the compensation packages
of top financial executives at firms that received bailouts. Many of the
biggest bailout beneficiaries balked at the proposed salary limits and strove
to get out from under them by paying the government back.
More ominously for the
financial institutions, many members of Congress marched into 2010 with a
determination to regulate them more closely. The House passed a bill in 2009
that for the first time would bring exotic financial instruments under review
by federal regulators. The bill would also establish a single agency to protect
financial consumers and guarantee shareholders a chance to vote on the
compensation packages of corporate executives. The Senate planned to take up
the issue in 2010.
An Uncertain Future
Despite the year-end sighs of
relief over the improving economy, the economic destruction had not necessarily
run its course. Many banks that survived the crisis were badly bruised by the
collapse of the housing market and remained less willing than before to provide
the credit that greases all capitalist economies. Huge government budget
deficits, designed to facilitate economic growth in the short term, loomed like
dark clouds on the horizon, threatening inflation and currency devaluations.
Low interest rates encouraged immediate business activity, but, like budget
deficits, they could ultimately feed inflation. International trade, which
suffered as countries hunkered down and adopted “me-first” policies, held below
precrisis levels. In the U.S., foreclosure rates were high and rising. Nearly
one house in four was worth less than what the occupants owed on the mortgage,
and similar problems in commercial real estate were mounting.
Despite this, harbingers of
prosperity were not hard to find. Stock markets turned robustly upward, with
the DJIA making up half of its losses by year-end 2009. Although unemployment
in the U.S. reached a peak of 10.2%, its highest level since 1983, it declined
to 10%, and the 2.2% annual growth rate that the economy registered in the
third quarter suggested future job growth. Economists even took heart from the
plight of Dubai World, a government-owned developer in Dubai, U.A.E., that
could not pay back $3.5 billion in loans by a December 14 deadline. Just in the
nick of time, fellow emirate Abu Dhabi bailed out Dubai with $10 billion. Not
only was that enough to get Dubai World well beyond its immediate default date,
but it also proved that not every financial cough would mean pneumonia for the
global economy. (Source: http://www.britannica.com/EBchecked/topic/1661642/The-Great-Recession-of-2008-09-Year-In-Review-2009/286636/The-US-Response)
The Great Depression
The next step in a mounting
spiral of international crisis came with theonset of a global economic
depression, which hit the headlines with the crash of key Western banks in 1929
but which in fact had begun, sullenly, in many parts of the world economy even
earlier.
The depression resulted from
new problems in the industrial economy of Europe and the United States,
combined with the long-term weakness in economies, like those of Latin America,
that depended on sales of cheap exports in the international market. The result
was a worldwide collapse that spared only a few economies and brought political
and economic pressures on virtually every society.
Causation
The impact of the First World
War on the European economy had led to several rocky years into the early 1920s.
War-induced inflation was a particular problem in Germany, as prices soared
daily and ordinary purchases required huge quantities of currency. Forceful
government action finally resolved this crisis in 1923, but only by a massive
devaluation of the mark, which did nothing to restore lost savings. More
generally, a sharp, brief recession in 1920 and 1921 had reflected other postwar
dislocations, though by 1923 production levels had regained or surpassed prewar
levels. Great Britain, an industrial pioneer that was already victim of a loss
of dynamism before the war, recovered more slowly, in part because of its
unusually great dependence on an export market now open to wider competition.
Structural problems affected
other areas of Europe besides Britain and lasted well beyond the predictable
readjustments to peacetime. Farmers throughout much of the Western world
including the United States faced almost chronic overproduction of food and
resulting low prices. Food production had soared in response to wartime needs,
and then during postwar inflation many farmers, both in western Europe and in
North America, borrowed heavily to buy new equipment, overconfident that their
good markets would be sustained. But rising European production combined with
large imports from the Americas sent prices down, which made debts harder to repay.
One response was continued flight from the countryside, as urbanization continued.
Remaining farmers were hard-pressed and unable to sustain high demand for
manufactured goods.
Thus, although economies in
nations such as France and Germany seemed to have recovered by 1925, there were
continued problems: the fears inflation had generated, which in turn limited
the capacity of governments to respond to other problems, plus the weaknesses
in the buying power of key groups. In this situation, part of the mid- decade
prosperity rested on exceedingly fragile grounds. Loans from United States
banks to various European enterprises helped sustain demand for goods, but on
condition that additional loans pour in to help pay off the resultant debts.
Furthermore, most of the
dependent areas in the world economy, colonies and noncolonies alike, were
suffering badly. Pronounced tendencies toward overproduction developed in the
smaller nations of eastern Europe, which sent agricultural goods to western
Europe, as well as among tropical producers in Africa and Latin America. Here,
continued efforts to win export revenue drove local estate owners to drive up
output in such goods as coffee, sugar, and rubber. As European governments and
businessmen organized their African colonies for more profitable exploitation,
they set up large estates devoted to goods of this type. Again, production
frequently exceeded demand, which drove prices and earnings down not only in Africa
but also in Latin America. This meant in turn that many colonies and dependent
economies were unable to buy many industrial exports, which weakened demand for
Western products precisely when output tended to rise amid growing United
States and Japanese competition.
Governments of the leading
industrial nations provided scant leadership during the emerging crisis of the
1920s. Knowledge of economics was often feeble amid a Western leadership group
not noteworthy for its quality even in more conventional areas. Nationalistic
selfishness predominated. Western nations were more concerned about insisting
on repayment of any debts owed to them or about constructing tariff barriers to
protect their own industries than in facilitating balanced world economic
growth. Protectionism, in particular, as practiced even by traditionally free-trade
Great Britain and by the many new nations in eastern Europe, simply reduced market
opportunities and made a bad situation worse. By the later 1920s employment in
key export industrial sectors in the West - coal (also beset by new competition
from imported oil), iron, and textiles - began to decline, the foretaste of
more general collapse.
The Debacle
The formal advent of depression
occurred in October 1929, when the New York stock market crashed. Stock values
tumbled, as investors quickly lost confidence in issues that had been pushed ridiculously
high. United States banks, which had depended heavily on their stock
investments, rapidly echoed the financial crisis, and many institutions failed,
dragging their depositors along with them. Even before this collapse, Americans
had begun to call back earlier loans to Europe. Yet the European credit
structure depended extensively on American loans, which had fueled some
industrial expansion but also less productive investments such as German
reparation payments and the construction of fancy town halls and other
amenities. In Europe, as in the United States, many commercial enterprises existed
on the basis not of real production power but of continued speculation. When
one piece of the speculative spiral was withdrawn, the whole edifice quickly
collapsed. Key bank failures in Austria and Germany followed the American
crisis. Throughout most of the industrial West, investment funds dried up as
creditors went bankrupt or tried to pull in their horns.
With investment receding,
industrial production quickly began to fall, beginning in the industries that
produced capital goods and extending quickly to consumer products fields.
Falling production - levels dropped by as much as one-third by 1932 - meant
falling employment and lower wages, which in turn withdrew still more demand
from the economy and led to further hardship. The existing weakness of some
markets, such as the farm sector or the nonindustrial world, was exacerbated as
demand for foods and minerals plummeted. New and appalling problems developed
among workers - now out of jobs or suffering from reduced hours and reduced pay
- as well as the middle classes. The depression, in sum, fed on itself, growing
steadily worse from 1929 to 1933. Even countries initially less hard hit, such
as France and Italy, saw themselves drawn into the vortex by 1931.
In itself, the Great Depression
was not entirely unprecedented. Previous periods had seen slumps triggered by
bank failures and overspeculation, yielding several years of falling
production, unemployment, and real hardship. But the intensity of the Great
Depression had no precedent in the brief history of industrial societies. Its
duration was also unprecedented; in many countries full recovery came only
after a decade, and only with the forced production schedules provoked by World
War II. The depression was also more marked than its antecedents because it came
on the heels of so much other distress - the economic hardships of war, for
example, and the catastrophic inflation of the 1920s - and because it caught most
governments utterly unprepared to cope.
The depression was more, of
course, than an economic event. It reached into countless lives, creating
hardship and tension that would be recalled even as the crisis itself eased.
Loss of earnings, loss of work, or simply fears that loss would come could
devastate people at all social levels. The suicides of ruined investors in New
York were paralleled by the vagrants' camps and begging that spread among
displaced workers. The statistics were grim: up to one-third of all blue-collar
workers in the West lost their jobs for prolonged periods. White-collar
unemployment, though not quite as severe, was also unparalleled. In Germany
600,000 of four million white-collar workers had lost their jobs by 1931.
Graduating students could not find work or had to resort to jobs they regarded
as insecure or demeaning. Figures of six million overall unemployed in Germany
and 22 percent of the labor force unemployed in Britain were statistics of
stark misery and despair. Families were disrupted, as men felt emasculated at
their inability to provide and women and children were disgusted at authority
figures whose authority was now hollow. In some cases wives and mothers found
it easier to gain jobs in a low-wage economy than their husbands did, and
although this development had some promise in terms of new opportunities for
women, it could also be confusing for standard family roles. Again, the agony
and personal disruption of the depression constituted no short shock. For many
it was desperately prolonged, with renewed recession around 1937 and with unemployment
still averaging ten percent or more in many countries by 1939.
Just as World War I had been,
the depression was an event that blatantly contradicted the optimistic
assumptions of the later 19th century. To many, it showed the fragility of any
idea of progress, any belief that Western civilization was becoming more
humane. To still more it challenged the notion that standard Western
governments - the parliamentary democracies - were able to control their own
destinies. And because it was a second catastrophic event within a generation,
the depression led to even more extreme results than the war itself had done -
more bizarre experiments, more paralysis in the face of deepening despair.
Worldwide Impact
Just as the depression had been
caused by a combination of specifically Western problems and wider weaknesses
in the world economy, so its effects had both Western twists and international
repercussions.
A few economies were buffered
from the depression. The Soviet Union, busy building an industrial society
under communist control, had cut off all but the most insignificant economic
ties with other nations under the heading "socialism in one country."
The result placed great hardships on many Russian people, called to sustain
rapid industrial development without outside capital, but it did prevent
anything like a depression during the 1930s. Soviet leaders pointed with pride
to the lack of serious unemployment and steadily rising production rates, in a
telling contrast with the miseries of Western capitalism at the time.
For most of the rest of the
world, however, the depression worsened an already bleak economic picture.
Western markets could absorb fewer commodity imports as production fell and
incomes dwindled. Hence the nations that produced foods and raw materials saw
prices and earnings drop even more than before. Unemployment rose rapidly in
the export sectors of the Latin American economy, creating a major political
challenge not unlike that faced by the Western leaders.
Japan, as a new industrial
country still heavily dependent on export earnings for financing its imports of
essential fuel and raw materials, was hit hard too. The Japanese silk industry,
an export staple, was already suffering from the advent of artificial silk-like
fibers produced by Western chemical giants. Now luxury purchases collapsed,
leading to severe unemployment and, again, a crucial political crisis.
Between 1929 and 1931, the
value of Japanese exports plummeted by 50 percent. Workers' real income dropped
by almost one-third, and there were over three million unemployed. Depression
was compounded by bad harvests in several regions, leading to rural begging and
near-starvation.
The Great Depression, though
most familiar in its Western dimensions, was a truly international collapse, a
sign of the tight bonds and serious imbalances that had developed in world
trading patterns. The results of the collapse, and particularly the varied responses
to it, are best traced in individual cases. For Latin America, the depression
marked a pronounced stimulus to new kinds of effective political action, and
particularly greater state involvement in planning and direction. New
government vigor did not cure the economic effects of the depression, which
escaped the control of most individual states, but it did set an important new
phase in the civilization's political evolution. For Japan, the depression
increased suspicions of the West and helped promote new expansionism designed
among other things to win more assured markets in Asia. In the West the
depression led to new welfare programs that stimulated demand and helped
restore confidence, but it also led to radical social and political experiments
such as German Nazism. What was common in this welter of reactions was the intractable
global quality of the depression itself, which made it impossible for any
purely national policy to restore full prosperity. Even Nazi Germany, which
boasted of regaining full employment, continued to suffer from low wages and
other dislocations aside from its obvious and growing dependence on military
production.
The reactions to the
depression, including a sense of weakness and confusion in many quarters inside
and outside policy circles, finally helped to bring the final great crisis of
the first half of the 20th century: a second, and more fully international,
world war. (Source: http://history-world.org/great_depression.htm)
Sources:
http://www.britannica.com/EBchecked/topic/1661642/The-Great-Recession-of-2008-09-Year-In-Review-2009/286636/The-US-Response
Adas, Michael. One-Half Century Of Crisis, 1914-1945. 1992 http://history-world.org/great_depression.htm
Clark, Josh. http://money.howstuffworks.com/recession-and-depression2.htm
No comments:
Post a Comment